<< Hide Menu
4 min readโขjune 18, 2024
Jeanne Stansak
dylan_black_2025
Jeanne Stansak
dylan_black_2025
Last section, we learn about aย monopoly. A monopoly is a market structure in which the entire market is run by one firm who has complete control over the price and quantity produced. In aย uniformly-pricing monopoly, the monopolist charges only one price - the demand price at the point where MR = MC. In a monopoly, MR is less than D because a monopoly must charge all consumers the same price, meaning they cannot take advantage of different willingnesses to pay. Even if the first consumer is willing to pay 5, they must charge $5.ย
However, the monopolist doesn'tย have to uniformly-price (barring laws forcing them to). This section will discussย price-discrimination, the process by which a monopolist smashes consumer surplus and charges every consumer a different price - their exact willingness to pay.ย
Price discrimination is a practice used by monopolies in which specific products are sold to different buyers and each consumer is charged the highest price that they are willing and able to pay. The price they are charged is based on their purchasing power and their demand elasticity. If a customer is willing to pay a lot, they're charged a lot. If they're willing to pay a little (up to the price where MR = MC), they're charged a little.
There are three conditions that need to be present in order for a monopoly to practice price discrimination:
There are many differences between a regular monopoly and one that price discriminates. Take a look at the table below for more information.
Characteristics | Pure Monopoly | Price Discriminating Monopoly |
Demand & MR | D > MR | D = MR |
Efficiency | Productivelyย and allocatively inefficient | Allocatively efficient, productively inefficient |
Economic Profits | Smaller long-run economic profts | Larger long-run economic profits |
Consumer Surplus | Some consumer surplus | Zero consumer surplus |
In perfect price discrimination (also called first degree price discrimination), demand exactly equals marginal revenue because we're able to earn exactly the additional willingness to pay for each additional unit, unlike before. Thus, we have three main curves on our graph: MC, which stays the same, D = MR, which is downward sloping, and ATC, which also doesn't change.
Total revenue looks like a trapezoid going down the demand curve, since we make different amounts of revenue per consumer.
Total cost is the same as always - the rectangle formed by ATC and the price.
The following graph shows profit in a price discriminating monopoly:
In price discrimination, consumer surplus is wiped out to ZERO. This is because every consumer is charged exactly their willingness to pay, so they always make no surplus. Instead, this is converted to producer surplus, since the monopolist gets what would be their additional willingness to pay. However, we also have no deadweight loss, since we now are producing where P = MC.
By price discriminating, a monopolistic firm will increase its economic profits. A pure monopoly charges a single price, where a price discriminator will charge each consumer at different prices. This eliminates consumer surplus and turns that into revenue, which in turn increases the economic profits that are earned by the firm.
Examples of various situations where monopolies are price discriminating include:
ยฉ 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.